NewYorkUniversity
LawReview

Topics

Banking Law

Results

Green Monetary Policy: What the Federal Reserve System Can Learn from the European Central Bank

Soomin Shin

Central banks like the European Central Bank (ECB) have started incorporating climate change considerations into their monetary policy tools. This Note refers to this phenomenon as green monetary policy (GMP). Given the crucial role of central banks and other monetary authorities in bank supervision and regulation, GMP has emerged as a solution to tackle the continued financing of fossil fuels and industries that have accelerated climate change. Among central banks, the ECB has emerged as a leader in GMP. However, the United States Federal Reserve Board (the Fed) has signaled a refusal to engage in any climate policymaking, including GMP. This paper argues that the Fed should follow the ECB by implementing GMP, given the central banks’ similar structure, general tools of monetary policy, and monetary policy-related goals. Although the Fed, unlike the ECB, does not have a secondary mandate to support general economic policies including environmental and climate-related goals, the Fed and the ECB are both mandated to promote price stability and act as a supervisor of financial risk. This Note analyzes the implications of the potential implementation of GMP by the Fed, comparing it to the ECB’s GMP, structure, and statutory mandates. It also explores key concerns and counterarguments in the literature against Fed implementation of GMP, which deal with independence, accountability, and mission creep. Despite these concerns, the Fed should continue to research climate change’s impact on macroeconomic stability and apply climate change considerations in its collateral policy, as the ECB has already done.

Why Have Uninsured Depositors Become De Facto Insured?

Michael Ohlrogge

The recent failures of Silicon Valley Bank and First Republic have drawn attention to how rare it is for uninsured depositors at a failed bank to bear losses. In this paper, I show that ubiquitous rescues of uninsured depositors represent a recent phenomenon dating only to 2008. For many years prior to that, uninsured depositor losses were the norm. I also show that the rise of uninsured depositor rescues has coincided with a dramatic increase in FDIC costs of resolving failed banks, which I estimate resulted in at least $45 billion in additional resolution expenses over the past fifteen years. I estimate that only $4 billion of this rise in costs is attributable to transfers to uninsured depositors, with $41 billion attributable to new inefficiencies in the resolution process.

The rise in uninsured depositor rescues has resulted from a shift by the FDIC to almost always resolve failed banks by selling them as a whole (including both insured and uninsured deposits) to an acquirer, generally with a generous subsidy provided by the FDIC. This Article also presents evidence to suggest that, despite the FDIC’s statutory mandate to use the least-cost means of protecting insured depositors of a failed bank, these whole-bank sales are frequently not the most efficient means of resolving failed banks. Next, I present evidence for two probable causes of this shift. First, during the 2008 crisis, the FDIC may have initially been forced to sell whole banks to acquirers because it lacked capacity to handle the influx of failures through other means. This may have established an institutional inertia that has maintained the practice long after the exigencies that necessitated it have cleared. Second, I suggest that the FDIC may have experienced mission creep, taking it upon itself to rescue uninsured depositors whenever possible, even though U.S. law requires the FDIC to seek authorization from the U.S. President whenever it deems it necessary to deviate from least-cost resolution methods. I show that such mission creep has occurred twice in the past, and that Congress has successfully intervened to stop it in 1951 and 1991.